189 U.S. App. D.C. 250 584 F.2d 408

584 F.2d 408

FARMERS UNION CENTRAL EXCHANGE et al., Petitioners, v. FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION * and the United States of America, Williams Pipe Line Co., Explorer Pipeline Co., Intervenors.

No. 76-2138.

United States Court of Appeals, District of Columbia Circuit.

Argued April 5, 1978.

Decided June 27, 1978.

Rehearing Denied July 25, 1978.

Certiorari Denied Nov. 27,1978.

See 99 S.Ct. 596.

*251John M. Cleary, Washington, D. C., with whom Frederic L. Wood, Washington, D. C., was on the brief, for petitioners.

Ron M. Landsman, Atty., Dept, of Justice, Washington, D. C., with whom John J. Powers, III, Atty., Dept, of Justice, Washington, D. C., was on the brief, for respondent, the United States.

Christine N. Kohl, Atty., I. C. C., Washington, D. C., with whom Mark L. Evans, Gen. Counsel and Charles H. White, Jr., Associate Gen. Counsel, Washington, D. C., were on the brief, for I. C. C.

J. Paul Douglas, Atty., Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Washington, D. C., with whom Philip R. Telleen, Atty., Federal Energy Regulatory Commission, Washington, D. C., was on the pleadings, for respondent, Federal Energy Regulatory Commission.

Robert G. Bleakney, Jr., Boston, Mass., with whom David M. Schwartz and Robert L. Calhoun, Washington, D. C., were on the brief, for intervenor, Williams Pipe Line Co.

Donald W. Markham, Washington, D. C., with whom Jonathan B. Hill, Washington, D. C., was on the brief, for intervenor, Explorer Pipeline Co.

Hanford O’Hara, Atty., I. C. C., Washington, D. C., entered an appearance for I. C. C.

Robert B. Nicholson and Andrea Limmer, Attys., Dept, of Justice, Washington, D. C., entered appearances for respondent, United States.

Before McGOWAN, LEVENTHAL and WILKEY, Circuit Judges.

Opinion for the Court filed by McGOWAN, Circuit Judge.

*252McGOWAN, Circuit Judge:

Petitioners, a group of oil shippers, challenge an order of the Interstate Commerce Commission (ICC) sustaining (1) increased rates filed by intervenor Williams Pipe Line Co. (Williams) and (2) joint rates initiated by Williams and intervenor Explorer Pipeline Co. (Explorer), as against claims that the former are unreasonably excessive, see 49 U.S.C. § l(5)(a), and the latter are discriminatory, see id § 2, and illegally preferential, see id. § 3(1).

This review proceeding is unique in that, while pending before us awaiting briefing and oral argument, jurisdiction over the rates in question was transferred by Congress from the ICC to the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission (FERC), and the latter has been substituted for the ICC as the respondent agency. FERC has advised this court that it takes no position with respect to the merits of the order under attack, and urges us rather to forego adjudication on the merits in favor of a remand of the case to it so that it can formulate, independently to the ICC, the regulatory principles it finds to be suitable for application in this new area of responsibility committed to it. The United States, a statutory respondent, purporting to see deficiencies in the ICC’s decision, supports FERC’s remand request.

The court, now having had the benefit of full briefing and oral argument of the merits by all parties except FERC, has concluded, to the extent and for the reasons hereinafter appearing, to remand the case to FERC for determination by it, under its new authority, of the compatibility of the subject rates with 49 U.S.C. § l(5)(a), and, in light of its findings thereon, for examination of the preference issue under id. § 3(1). As to the existence of discrimination, however, petitioners’ failure properly to raise the issue before the ICC mandates our affirmance of that agency’s decision insofar as it is based on id. § 2.

I

Williams, an independent common carrier, is a relatively new entrant in the oil pipeline transmission industry, having begun doing business in 1966 with the purchase of Great Lakes Pipe Line Co. (Great Lakes). It acquired the physical assets of Great Lakes from eight petroleum producer-owners for $287.6 million — the highest among the competitive bids received.1 The pipeline system thus acquired serves a large portion of the Midwest, with connections in such producing and refining cities as Tulsa, Fargo, Lincoln, and Topeka, and in such consuming cities as East St. Louis, Chicago, and Minneapolis. By interconnecting with intervenor Explorer Pipeline Co. (Explorer) at Tulsa, Williams also may connect refineries located along the Gulf Coast of Texas and Louisiana with consumers in the Midwest.

Petitioners are a group of oil producers and refiners located primarily in the Great Plains area who historically have used the Great Lakes-Williams pipeline system to transport their petroleum products to the Midwest. In late 1971 and early 1972, Williams informed them that it was raising its rates by approximately 15 percent (or 3 cents a barrel) across the board. At the same time as it generally increased its rates, Williams, together with Explorer, initiated joint rates for through service from the Gulf Coast to the Midwest. These joint rates are uniformly 9.5 cents a barrel lower than the combination of Williams’ and Explorer’s local rates.

Shortly after the appropriate tariffs were filed with the ICC, petitioners made them the subject of complaints under the provi*253sions of the Interstate Commerce Act which, inter alia, regulates oil pipeline rates, 49 U.S.C. § l(l)(b). Petitioners’ protests led the ICC to initiate investigations into the lawfulness of both sets of rates, although the disputed rates have remained in effect without suspension since their inception, pending the outcome of these proceedings. Although many claims were originally raised by the parties, the course of administrative consideration has left three major issues of import on appeal.

First, petitioners argue that Williams’ rate increases for the transportation of oil in the area formerly served by Great Lakes are unreasonable under id. § l(5)(a),2 because they are derived from an inflated valuation rate base3 and allow an excessive rate of return on that rate base (10%); and further because certain operating ex-penses4 and tax allowances5 used by Williams in computing its rates were unreasonable. Second, petitioners claim that by charging them local rates to transport their oil from the Great Plains to the Midwest while charging the Gulf Coast shippers less (per mile) — under the joint Williams-Explorer rates — to transport their oil to the same destinations, intervenors are giving *254the Gulf Coast shippers an unjust preference. Id. § 3(1).6 Finally, petitioners argue that by unevenly dividing the joint rate revenues with Explorer, Williams is giving the eight Gulf Coast shippers that jointly own Explorer a discriminatory rebate. Id. § 2.7 Petitioners asked the ICC to order Williams to lower — and Williams and Explorer to readjust — the rates in question, and to pay reparations plus interest, costs, and attorneys’ fees.

Petitioners do not contest the propriety of the procedures used by the ICC in adjudicating their complaints. The administrative law judge announced his decision favorable to Williams on June 6, 1974, after holding several days of formal hearings in 1972 and 1973 and after considering copious written submissions. Petroleum Products, Williams Bros. Pipe Line Co. (unpublished initial decision) [hereinafter referred to as Initial Decision and cited to Joint Appendix (JA)]. Exceptions were filed by the petitioners on both sets of issues, thereby entitling them to consideration by a three-commissioner division of the ICC. On the basis of the record as well as the exceptions and replies filed by the parties, the division, one commissioner dissenting, accepted the findings of the administrative law judge. Petroleum Products, Williams Bros. Pipe Line Co., 355 I.C.C. 102, 126 (1975) [hereinafter referred to as Williams I].

Petitioners next asked the entire Commission to reconsider the case, arguing that it involved “matters of general transportation importance” — the standard that must be met to secure reconsideration by the full Commission. Although asserting that the issues did not rise to the requisite level of importance, the full Commission felt that reconsideration of the record, as supplemented by written submissions by the parties, was merited “because of the relative dearth of precedent concerning petroleum pipeline rates, and in view of the substantial sums of money at issue. ...” Petroleum Products, Williams Bros. Pipe Line Co., 355 I.C.C. 479, 481 (1976) [hereinafter referred to as Williams II]. In an opinion filed December 3, 1976, the full Commission, one commissioner dissenting and two not participating, affirmed the findings of the administrative law judge and the division, id., and petitioners sought direct review by this court.

II

A.

In 1906, the Interstate Commerce Act of Feb. 4, 1887, c. 104, 24 Stat. 379, was amended by the Hepburn Act to include companies engaged in the “transportation of oil . by pipe line” among the common carriers subject to regulation thereunder. Act of June 29, 1906, c. 3591, § 1, 34 Stat. 584. Yet, while pipeline companies joined railroads, and were later joined by motor carriers, as regulatory subjects of the Interstate Commerce Act, those companies never faced the degree of regulation to which the vehicular common carriers were subject. Thus, while under the *255same duty as railroads and/or motor carriers to fúrnish or allow continuous transportation, 49 U.S.C. §§ 1(1), 1(4), 7, to establish, file, and publish reasonable, nondiscriminatory rates subject to ICC approval, id. §§ 1(5), 3(1), 4(1), 6, 15(1), to avoid certain pooling relationships, id. § 5(1), to file certain financial reports, and to use certain accounting procedures subject to ICC specifications, id. §§ 20(1), (2), (4), (5), pipeline companies have none of the special obligations imposed upon the vehicular regulatees under the Act concerning acquisitions, mergers, corporate affiliates, uniform cost and revenue accounting, issuance of securities, and corporate or financial reorganizations. Id. §§ 5(2) — (13), 20(3), 20a, 20b, 20c. For this reason, we may infer a congressional intent to allow a freer play of competitive forces among oil pipeline companies than in other common carrier industries and, as such, we should be especially loath uncritically to import public utilities notions into this area without taking note of the degree of regulation and of the nature of the regulated business. See J. Bonbright, Principles of Public Utility Rates 4 — 5 (1961).

Consequently, beyond the general outlines of the Interstate Commerce Act, and the specific provisions therein dealing with ratemaking, see notes 2, 6 & 7 supra, we have little to rely on in constructing a theory of oil pipeline ratemaking. Although the Act, as amended by the Valuation Act, 37 Stat. 701 (1913), does provide the ICC with the wherewithal to gather the information necessary to determine the “valuation” of railroads and oil pipeline companies, 49 U.S.C. § 19a, see note 3 supra, we see nothing in the Valuation Act that requires the agency to translate its valuation authority into a mandatory approach to ratemaking or that makes a valuation approach inevitably reasonable.8

ICC precedent provides little additional guidance as to appropriate ratemaking methodology for the oil pipeline industry. In the four published opinions in which it has heretofore discussed oil pipeline rate-making, the ICC adopted the valuation rate base without discussion, or even explicit recognition, of alternative bases. Reduced Pipe Line Rates and Gathering Charges, 243 I.C.C. 115 (1940) [hereinafter Reduced Rates I], reopened, 272 I.C.C. 375 (1948) [hereinafter Reduced Rates II]; Petroleum *256 Rail Shippers’ Ass’n v. Alton & So. R. R., 243 I.C.C. 589 (1941); Minnelusa Oil Corp. v. Continental Pipe Line Co., 258 I.C.C. 41 (1944). Nonetheless, the ICC’s use in the 1940’s of the “fair value” method is not hard to explain — and in that explanation lies an important reason to reexamine the continued viability of the decisions announced during that era.

The ICC’s primary experience with rate-making prior to the 1940’s involved railroads, as to which a landmark Supreme Court case had appeared to mandate the fair value method of ratemaking. Smyth v. Ames, 169 U.S. 466, 546-47, 18 S.Ct. 418, 42 L.Ed. 819 (1898); see note 8 supra. See also St. Louis & O’Fallon Ry. Co. v. United States, 279 U.S. 461, 49 S.Ct. 384, 73 L.Ed. 798 (1929). Subsequently, the Supreme Court’s endorsement on this method was extended to other areas. E. g., Southwestern Bell Tel. Co. v. Missouri Pub. Serv. Comm’n, 262 U.S. 276, 43 S.Ct. 544, 67 L.Ed. 981 (1923). Although under the impetus of Justice Brandéis’ concurring opinion in the last-cited case, id. at 289-312, 43 S.Ct. 544, the Supreme Court during the 1930’s began to countenance experimentation with other ratemaking approaches, e. g., Railroad Comm’n of California v. Pacific Gas Co., 302 U.S. 388, 399, 58 S.Ct. 334, 82 L.Ed. 319 (1938), by this time the ICC had established a firm practice of using the valuation method. E. g., Petroleum Rail Shippers, supra. Thus, the ICC practice, reflected in the four pipeline rate cases cited earlier, of using a valuation rate base had become ensconced in that agency’s decision by 1944, when the Supreme Court decisively reversed its field and became openly critical of talismanic reliance on “fair value.” FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 320 U.S. 591, 601, 64 S.Ct. 281, 88 L.Ed. 333 (1944). Moreover, between the time that Hope’s implications became clear and the ICC’s consideration of this case, that agency did not have occasion to discuss the principles of oil pipeline ratemaking.9 As such, we are left to draw our conclusions about this case based on a series of ICC opinions that arose in a ratemaking environment that has since been dramatically altered by the Supreme Court.10

In addition to the significant changes in the relevant legal environment since the ICC’s 1940’s decisions, important economic transformations have occurred. First, that agency’s only actual comparison in the 1940’s of the “valuation” of pipeline assets and the actual investment therein “as carried on [the pipeline companies’] books” (i. e., apparently, original cost) shows that in a majority of cases “the valuations] found by the Commission were materially lower than the carriers’ investment. ...” Reduced Rates I, supra, 243 I.C.C. at 138 (emphasis added). This 1940’s situation is *257in marked contrast to that experienced in today’s inflationary economy wherein valuation typically exceeds investment by a substantial amount.11

Second, based on rather detailed analyses of economic conditions facing the industry in the 1940’s, the Commission’s 1940’s decisions determined that oil pipeline rates should allow carriers to recover operating expenses plus no more than either an 8 percent return on value for transmission of crude oil or crude oil plus refined petroleum products, Reduced Rates II, supra, 272 I.C.C. at 376, 384 (rates upheld actually producing 7.6 percent rate of return); Minnelusa, supra, 258 I.C.C. at 54; Reduced Rates I, supra, 243 I.C.C. at 142, or a 10 percent return on value for transmission of gasoline. Petroleum Rail Shippers, supra, 243 I.C.C. at 663. The ICC pointed out that by 1940’s standards these rates of returns were

somewhat larger . . . than . would be reasonable to expect would be applied in industries of a more stable character, where the volume of traffic is more accurately predictable.

Minnelusa, supra, 258 I.C.C. at 54, accord, Petroleum Rail Shippers, supra, 243 I.C.C. at 661-62; Reduced Rates I, supra, 243 I.C.C. at 142.

In the Commission’s estimation, these “somewhat larger” rates of return were justified on the one hand by the need to attract capital to the oil pipeline industry despite the higher-than-normal risks faced by carriers of petroleum products,12 and especially of gasoline,13 and on the other hand, by the need to keep rates low enough to forestall the dangers of oligopolistic control of the oil pipeline industry by the big producers.14 Other factors considered by the ICC were the possibility of price fixing 15 and a history of “enormous” profits,16 the cost effects of greatly increased taxation during the 1930’s,17 the increased demand for oil products, the improved technology of pipeline transmission precipitated *258by World War II,18 and the prediction that economic forces would cause rates to drop regardless of ICC action.19 Notably, aside from brief discussions of increased labor costs, the ICC’s decisions make clear that operating costs other than taxes were relatively free from inflationary (or deflationary) influences from 1937 to 1947.20

To the extent that economic conditions facing the oil pipeline industry have changed since 1948 — and, in light of the modern onslaught of inflation, petroleum shortages, and reliance on imports, as well as the maturing of the industry itself, we may readily assume they have — the conclusions of the ICC in its earlier cases as to appropriate rates of return are equally as much artifacts of a bygone era as is its reliance then on a valuation rate base.

Finally, the ICC’s 1940’s cases recede even further into the background when it is realized that the ICC has been replaced by FERC as the government agency charged with watching over oil pipeline rates.21 The transfer of authority to FERC occurred during the pendency of this petition pursuant to the Department of Energy Organization Act (the DOE Act), Pub.L.No.95-91, § 402(b), 91 Stat. 584 (1977), effectuated, Executive Order No. 12009, 42 Fed.Reg. 46267 (Sept. 15,1977), implemented, 42 Fed. Reg. 55534 (Oct. 17, 1977). Although, the DOE Act provides that litigation commenced before the transfer shall continue, with “appeals taken, and judgments rendered . . . as if this Act had not been enacted,”22 as regards the substantive administrative law applicable in this case, the transfer further unsettles the foundations on which we must adjudicate this petition. Thus, it removes the stabilizing influence of the courts’ usual desire to afford an administrative agency some latitude over time to *259develop its own approach to the regulatory tasks delegated to it by Congress. See Permian Basin Area Rate Cases, 390 U.S. 747, 790, 88 S.Ct. 1344, 20 L.Ed.2d 312 (1968). Here, the transfer of authority has deprived us of even the possibility of endorsing ICC’s attempt to develop such an approach, and, in fact, has created the likelihood that anything we say will inhibit FERC from freely developing its approach in the future. That FERC has refused to adopt the ICC’s position in this case, and — joined by the Antitrust Division of the Department of Justice — has asked that the case be remanded to it, illustrates this problem.23

This background should explain our reluctance to embark on the first federal judicial foray into the area of oil pipeline ratemaking.24 In this endeavor, beyond the statute’s admonition that rates be “just and reasonable,” we. must rely almost entirely on the ICC’s opinions in this case. Moreover, as the next section demonstrates, those opinions are characterized by analytical difficulties that undermine their usefulness in resolving the overall reasonableness of the assailed rates.

B.

The parties have joined issue over the ICC’s treatment of five criteria they deem crucial to the reasonableness of Williams’ rate increases: rate base, rate of return, depreciation costs, tax treatment, and certain items of operating expenses. See notes 2-5 supra and accompanying text. In reaching our conclusion that the ICC’s decisions25 present problems that impel us to remand the reasonableness issue to its successor, FERC, we find it necessary to dwell on only the first three of these criteria.

Despite petitioners’ insistence on original cost less depreciation of all of Williams’ assets used in transmitting oil (i. e., $101.1 million), and Williams’ somewhat tentative advocacy of purchase price ($287.6 million) as the appropriate rate base, the ICC used a “valuation” base. Williams I, supra, 351 I.C.C. at 108. This is calculated to be $167.6 million, id., based primarily on two factors listed in the Valuation Act, 49 U.S.C. § 19a — original cost, and the cost of reproduction new.26 All three decisions based their analyses of the rates on the percent return they allowed on valuation, so that the importance to all three of the valuation rate base cannot be gainsaid.27

*260Most prominent among the three opinions’ explanations of the use of the “fair value” method was that as the “traditional,” “customar[y],” and “well-established practice” of the ICC in oil pipeline cases, valuation ratemaking has “withstood the test of time.” Initial Decision, supra, JA at 1608; see id. at 1605; Williams I, supra, 351 I.C.C. 105,107,113,114; Williams II, supra, 355 I.C.C. at 485. In support of this “tradition,” however, the opinions (when they cite any support at all) list only (1) the 1940’s oil pipeline cases discussed above, (2) the Commission’s history of computing valuations under the Valuation Act, and (3) the fact that the Commission’s mandatory accounting procedures for pipelines, see Uniform System of Accounts for Pipeline Companies, 337 I.C.C. 518, 523 (1970), are geared to the use of a valuation rate base. See Initial Decision, supra, JA at 1605, 1608; Williams I, supra, 351 I.C.C. at 107, 113.

As our previous discussion indicates, however, these three indicia of a tradition of fair value ratemaking are weak and outmoded. Both the oil pipeline precedents and the history of valuation computations under the Valuation Act are in large measure products of a bygone era of ratemaking ushered in by the Supreme Court in Smyth v. Ames in 1898 and ushered out by that same body in Hope Natural Gas in 1944. See notes 8-10 supra and accompanying text. To the extent that the ICC’s accounting rules derive their valuation focus from the 1940’s precedents and the Valuation Act, see Uniform System of Accounts, supra, 337 I.C.C. at 523, they, too, are subject to this same criticism.

Moreover, each of the three indicia suffers from infirmities of its own. First, even if we assume under Hope that valuation ratemaking might be capable of producing a viable “end result,” there is no assurance in the Commission’s 1940’s precedents — born as they were of peculiar post-depression, World War II, and post-War economic conditions — that such a result will occur in the 1970’s. Second, the Commission itself has seen fit to abandon its so-called tradition of valuation computation and ratemaking based thereon in the railroad area, which is equally subject to the Valuation Act. See note 9 supra. Finally, the ICC decision setting forth pipeline accounting rules states explicitly that it is

concerned . . . with accounting rules which are not necessarily dispositive of the manner in which expenditures will be treated in a proceeding to determine the reasonable level of particular rates.

Uniform System of Accounts, supra, 337 I.C.C. at 523. This last-quoted caveat should hardly have to be express. After all, it is rates, not bookkeeping, that the statute requires to be reasonable, and there is no assurance of record, at least, that reasonable accounting measures translate automatically into reasonable rates.

In sum, we are not persuaded by the Commission’s conclusion that “consistency and fairness” dictate resurrection of the “fair value” method last used thirty years ago. Williams II, supra, 355 I.C.C. at 484. To the extent that the method was wrongly grounded in the law at that time, it is no better off now. To the extent that it may have been rightly grounded in the economics of that day, the ICC has provided us *261with no reason to believe that three decades have not changed the situation. And, to the extent that Williams, having nothing else to depend on but the earlier cases, justifiably relied on them in adopting its rates, see id, the solution is not to perpetrate that reliance but to end it prospectively, without allowing reparations based on its occurrence in the past.28

Aside from the above arguments, the three ICC opinions mentioned but one other justification for the “fair value” method: the need for a ratemaking theory responsive to inflation.29 We have no quarrel with the ICC’s aspirations on this score. The Supreme Court has indicated that rates must be high enough to allow the regulatee to attract capital, and investors will be unlikely to invest if their earnings will not keep abreast of, and have some chance of exceeding, the rate of inflation. See FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co., supra, 320 U.S. at 603, 64 S.Ct. 281. Nonetheless, the ICC’s failure to assess the actual effects of inflation on Williams’ ability to attract capital, and its apparent “double counting” of concerns about inflation, see pp. 262-263 of 189 U.S.App.D.C., pp. 420-421 of 584 F.2d, infra, cast a shadow over its conclusion that a valuation rate base properly reflects inflation.

We find the ICC’s discussion of rate of return equally problematical. Here the total emphasis is on the 1940’s precedents: because 8-10 percent was a viable return for carriers of petroleum products from 1940 to 1948, it is said, so must it be today.30 Even more so than the choice of a reasonable rate base methodology, a “reasonable rate of return” determination must be the product of the economic moment. As noted earlier, the ICC’s choice in the 1940’s of the 8 and 10 percent figures turned on such “hazards” as the infancy of the gasoline industry, the likelihood of disruptive discoveries of new oil fields and the unidimensional nature of the product market served by pipeline carriers, as well as on such factors as unduly high profits in the past, high taxes, and a rapidly expanding economy relatively free of inflation. See notes 12-20 supra and accompanying text. Absent some accompanying assessment of how this complex of relevant factors has changed in thirty years, the ICC’s reliance *262on its antiquated precedents in determining a reasonable rate of return differs little from a rule that would require modern automobile accident damages to conform to those awarded by juries in 1940.31

Finally, we come to the depreciation charges allowed Williams as a cost that it may recoup through its rates. Just prior to Williams’ purchase of Great Lakes, it secured a Commission opinion that the Commission’s accounting instructions for pipeline carrier property accounts, 49 C.F.R. § 1204-3-1 et seq., applied to the purchase. JA at 202, 205. Under those instructions, Williams recorded its full purchase price of $287.6 million in its property account. Although the ICC informed Williams that this opinion did “not prejudice the Commission’s continuing rights and responsibilities with regard to rate determinations that may come before it,” JA at 205, Williams used this same method of valuing its wasting assets when calculating depreciation expenses for ratemaking purposes. Allowing this revaluation, for ratemaking as well as accounting purposes, of the Great Lakes-Williams property not only greatly increased depreciation charges from that point forward, but it also withdrew any recognition that rate payers had already been charged almost $100 million for depreciation by Great Lakes.

In upholding this operating expense calculation, the Commission did little more than (1) note the calculation’s congruence with its reporting and accounting rules, especially as discussed in Uniform System of Accounts, supra, and (2) point out the inability of petitioner’s recommended original cost approach to keep pace with inflated property values. Williams II, supra, 355 I.C.C. at 489. Once again, we cannot countenance the ICC’s current unexplained insistence on irrevocably hitching its ratemaking theory to its accounting rules. This linkage is especially troublesome because, when it wrote those rules, the Commission expressly denied them any such controlling impact on rates. See p. 260 of 189 U.S. App.D.C., p. 418 of 584 F.2d supra. It supported that express denial of linkage with a reminder that the ICC traditionally did not tie rates to “investment as shown on the carriers’ books, but rather [to] . valuations [computed] pursuant to the [Valuation Act].” Uniform System of Accounts, supra, 337 I.C.C. at 523. Hence, we are left with the additional unexplained anomaly of a valuation rate base coexisting with a purchase price depreciation base— hardly an “accepted . . . practice [ ].”32

The final irrationality is that the depreciation basis used, unlike original cost, valuation, and other possible approaches, allows depreciation charges, and thus the rates, to change dramatically from one day to the next — so long as a purchase of the assets intercedes — even though the cost of the carriers’ public service has not actually changed. It is true that occasional acquisitions of carriers at prices deemed currently reasonable might serve as a mechanism for accurately reflecting inflation’s impact on the value of such enterprises. We have our doubts, however, about either the desirability of encouraging acquisitions solely for *263this purpose, or of depending on their unpredictable occurrence to serve this function. In any case, the ICC in this case purports to have recognized inflation in figuring rate base (and perhaps even rate of return, see Williams II, supra, 355 I.C.C. at 487), so that a further inflation adjustment by way of increased depreciation charges would seem precipitous and itself unduly inflationary. See p. 261 of 189 U.S.App. D.C., p. 419 of 584 F.2d, supra.

The foregoing discussion illustrates our unease with the ICC’s findings regarding rate base, rate of return, and depreciation costs. Those three criteria, in turn, are important enough that doubts as to them must infect our view of the Commission’s ultimate finding of reasonableness.33 Nonetheless, were this a normal case, the limited scope of review under which we operate in these proceedings might require us to look beyond ICC’s rationale to the record itself, before we would be prepared to disapprove the Commission’s ultimate holding. See, e. g., Permian Basin, supra, 390 U.S. at 766-67, 88 S.Ct. 1344 (rate must be upheld if total effect is reasonable); FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co., supra, 320 U.S. at 603, 64 S.Ct. 281 (rate must be upheld, even if subject to theoretical “infirmities,” if “end result” is reasonable); The Second National Natural Gas Rate Cases, No. 76-2000, et a 1., slip op. at 18 (D.C.Cir. June 16, 1977) (“basic requirement [is] that there be support in the public record for what is done.”).

But this is not a normal ratemaking case — in large measure because we are at something of a loss to know what to look for should we resort to the public record. The lack of viable precedents in this area and thus of some semblance of established ratemaking theory undercuts any confidence we have that we can make a “reasonableness” determination in the absence of some significant assistance from the agency formerly charged with making that determination in the first instance. Moreover, the record appears to be incomplete in certain significant respects. See note 27 supra. What clinches our decision to remand on the reasonableness issue, however, is the fact that the agency now charged with that responsibility, FERC, has requested a remand so that it may begin its regulatory duties in this area with a clean slate. While “infirmities” in an agency’s methodology may not prevent us from affirming its otherwise supportable “reasonable rate” determination, see FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co., supra, 320 U.S. at 603, 64 S.Ct. 281, such “legal blemishes” may justify us in honoring that agency’s (or its successor’s) request that we remand its decision for reconsideration. Greater Boston Television Corp. v. FCC, 149 U.S.App.D.C. 322, 463 F.2d 268, 290 (1971); see note 22 supra.

Under the circumstances presented herein, it seems logical both to avail ourselves of some additional expertise before we plunge into this new and difficult area, and to allow the relevant administrative agency to attempt for itself to build a viable modem precedent for use in future cases that not only reaches the right result, but does so by way of ratemaking criteria free of the problems that appear to exist in the ICC’s approach. See note 24 supra. Cf. Permian Basin, supra, 390 U.S. at 790, 88 S.Ct. at 1372 (“breadth and complexity of the [agency’s ratemaking] responsibilities demand that it be given every reasonable opportunity to formulate methods of regulation appropriate for the solution of its intensely practical difficulties.”)

We realize that this disposition is at the expense of important finality concerns, embodied herein by intervenor Williams Pipeline Co. which has already faced six years of litigation and continues to face the possibility of reparations back to 1972 should its increased rates ultimately be found unreasonable. In subordinating those concerns to the public interest in an orderly ratemaking *264environment for oil pipeline transmissions, we rely on assurances from counsel for FERC that the agency will move this case through its ratemaking procedures with dispatch. Moreover, because Williams is hereby being exposed to the possibility of future operations under an unreasonable rate, not because of its own actions freely taken in the past, but because of FERC’s quasi-legislative action34 taken — with our sanction— with an eye to the future activities of all oil pipeline carriers, we are comforted by the apparent applicability of the rule that reparations are generally not available when the subject rates were in force as a result of quasi-legislative actions of a regulatory agency.35

For all of the foregoing reasons, we remand the case to FERC for determination of the reasonableness of Williams’ rates pursuant to 49 U.S.C. § l(5)(a). As a result of the necessity of remanding this issue, we are also constrained not to decide the prefer ence/prejudice issue under 49 U.S.C. § 3(1). See note 6 supra and accompanying text. This latter issue involves, inter alia, questions of (1) whether a disparity exists between Williams’ local rates and the through rates it has jointly initiated with Explorer, (2) if so, whether petitioners are competitively damaged thereby, and (3) if so, whether cost differentials or other “transportation conditions,” justify the disparity. See State of New York v. United States, 568 F.2d 887 (2d Cir. 1977); Chicago & E. Ill. R. R. v. United States, 384 F.Supp. 298, 300-01 (N.D.Ill.1974) (three-judge court), aff’d mem., 421 U.S. 956, 95 S.Ct. 1943, 44 L.Ed.2d 445 (1975). Since, on remand of the reasonableness issue, FERC will undoubtedly obtain additional evidence and conceivably could order that Williams lower its local rates, the nature of each of these three questions might change significantly on remand, so that any examination by us would be premature. Accordingly, FERC should also fully reconsider the section 3(1) issue.36

*265III

Petitioners also challenge the joint rates filed by Explorer and Williams, claiming that they work an illegal discrimination under section 2 of the Interstate Commerce Act, 49 U.S.C. § 2. Section 2 prohibits a carrier from granting a special rate or rebate to any shipper. See note 7 supra. The aim of this provision is to prevent personal favoritism from affecting rates. See Louisville & Nashville R. R. Co. v. Mottley, 219 U.S. 467, 478, 31 S.Ct. 265, 55 L.Ed. 297 (1911); Wight v. United States, 167 U.S. 512, 518, 17 S.Ct. 822, 42 L.Ed. 258 (1897).

Section 2 normally requires proof that despite a like kind of traffic moving under substantially similar circumstances, two shippers are being charged different prices. It has been accepted for at least ninety years that proof that a carrier charges shippers less for through goods than for those moving locally does not, without more, establish a violation of section 2. E. g., Union Pac. R. R. Co. v. United States, 117 U.S. 355, 6 S.Ct. 772, 29 L.Ed. 920 (1886); Texas & Pac. Ry. Co. v. ICC, 162 U.S. 197, 16 S.Ct. 666, 40 L.Ed. 940 (1896). Hence, petitioners cannot rest on proof that the joint Explorer-Williams rates are lower than the combination of their local rates.

Beyond introducing such clearly insufficient proof, petitioners note that together the bulk of the Gulf Coast shippers served by the Explorer-Williams interconnection own Explorer. Petitioners attempt to turn this affiliation into a rebate by challenging the division of rates between the two intervenors. They argue that by taking less than its due, Williams has left more to Explorer and to its shipper-owners (through dividends) than is their due, and accordingly has rebated some of the rates that Williams otherwise would have collected. Petitioners support this allegation with evidence allegedly showing that under the Explorer-Williams division of the joint rates Explorer receives the same price for transporting through oil as it does for transporting local oil under its individual rates, while Williams allegedly receives 9.5 cents per barrel less for through oil transported under the joint rates than it does for local oil transported over the same route under its individual rates. Thus, it is argued, Williams bore the full brunt of the “shrinkage” in through rates vis-a-vis the combined local rates, instead of dividing that shrinkage equally with Explorer.

Although dicta in Supreme Court cases suggest that divisions of rates between carriers is a matter between themselves, leaving shippers without standing to challenge them before the ICC,37 there also exist precedents for the view that unequal divisions of rates in situations involving shipper-owned carriers can result in rebates to the controlling shippers that are illegal under section 2. The Tap Line Cases, 234 U.S. 1, 28-29, 34 S.Ct. 741, 58 L.Ed. 1185 (1914) (dicta); see Divisions Received by Brimstone R. R. & Canal Co., 68 I.C.C. 375, 386-88 (1922), rev’d on other grounds, Brimstone R. R. & Canal Co. v. United States, 276 U.S. 104, 48 S.Ct. 282, 72 L.Ed. 487 (1928).

Unfortunately, petitioners did not discover these latter precedents and mold them into a coherent argument until they filed their reply brief in this court. Reply Brief of Petitioners at 20-22; cf. Brief of Petitioners, at 44; JA at 1526-32; 3789-95; 1703-08, 1891-92. To the extent that petitioners’ somewhat muddled arguments before the ICC implied that Williams’ joint rates were “a clear revenue drain” on Williams and thus unreasonably low under section 1(5), JA at 1528, the ICC found otherwise and petitioners have not appealed that finding before us. To the extent that petitioners appeared to be arguing “that the lesser combination rate is, itself, a form of discrimination exercised by” Williams, JA at 1527, they appeared merely to be repeat*266ing their argument under section 3(1) that the combination rates were preferential to Gulf Coast shippers and prejudicial to themselves. Hence, while we do not necessarily agree with the administrative law judge that whether “one carrier (public- or shipper-owned) is shortchanged in divisions with another carrier (public- or shipper-owned) is a matter . . . between the carriers [and one that is] foreign to the issue whether the joint rates . . . are discriminatory,” we do agree that in this case the issue was not properly raised.38 Accordingly, the ICC is affirmed on this issue.

The case is remanded to FERC for determination by it of whether Williams’ rates are reasonable and whether those rates in relation to the combined Williams-Explorer rates create an illegal preference. In other respects, the decision of the ICC is affirmed.

It is so ordered.

Farmers Union Central Exchange v. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
189 U.S. App. D.C. 250 584 F.2d 408

Case Details

Name
Farmers Union Central Exchange v. Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
Decision Date
Jun 27, 1978
Citations

189 U.S. App. D.C. 250

584 F.2d 408

Jurisdiction
District of Columbia

References

Referencing

Nothing yet... Still searching!

Referenced By

Nothing yet... Still searching!